Nudge (book review from blinkist)

We don’t always make decisions that are best for us in the long run.

Most people have a pretty clear idea of what’s good for them and what’s not. They are determined to eat healthily, save money for retirement and not smoke.
But when it comes to actually seeing these things through in everyday life, they often do the opposite: they eat unhealthily, they’re reckless with money and they smoke too much.
Unwise behaviors crop up in all parts of our lives, from eating habits to investment decisions to the way we structure our daily schedule. We grab a chocolate bar even though we know that an apple would be better for us; we hit snooze every time our alarm rings despite knowing this means we’ll only have to rush later.
Such behavioral patterns cause problems when quick decisions result in serious long-term consequences.For example, statistics show that when it comes to saving money, most US citizens save very little even though they know this can cause them trouble later.
If we suddenly lose our income due to illness or unemployment or have unexpected expenses like getting our car fixed, and have no savings to fall back on, we become angry about the irrational decisions we made in the past. And yet, despite knowing this, we continue to make financial decisions based on short-term rather than long-term goals.
We don’t always make decisions that are best for us in the long run.

We often make bad decisions based on either too little or overly complex information.

Why do we so often make decisions that aren’t really the best choices for us? In many cases, we simply have too little or too much information, or we can’t foresee the consequences of our actions. It’s only when we have, and can process, the right amount of information that we are in a place to make rational decisions.
For example, when we have to choose an ice cream flavor at an ice cream shop, we usually make that decision rather quickly. We see which flavors there are and we know from experience that strawberry ice cream tastes better than mango, i.e., we have all the necessary information and can process it rapidly.
However, we feel differently in more serious situations, like when deciding whether to take out a loan. After all, there are all different kinds of loans: purchases on account, deferrals, consumer loans, securities, preliminary financing, interim financing, and many more. Some of them have a fixed interest rate, others a variable; all of them have different additional costs. And this information isn’t exactly laid out in plain writing. Usually, it’s hidden in the small print on the bright and colorful advertisement.
In other words, even when we are privy to all the relevant information, it can still be difficult to sort it all out and compare the services objectively. Situations like this can make us feel completely overwhelmed.
We often make bad decisions based on either too little or overly complex information.

Human beings act mainly on gut feelings.

When we see a laughing baby, we can’t help but smile. That “decision” to smile is made unconsciously; our response occurs entirely on its own.
But when we want to figure out the answer to 347 x 12, we confront this task in a conscious way, because finding the answer requires an effort and takes some time.
These examples illustrate two different systems of thought:
1. In the case of the baby, we are using our Automatic System, i.e., our gut instinct.
2. In the case of the math problem, we are using the rational or Reflective System.
We don’t have the time or energy to reflect upon every little action we take on an average day, which is why we often let our Automatic System govern our actions.
It works well a lot of the time – but not all the time.
Grounded in simplifications, the Automatic System is often supported by a weak scaffolding of spontaneous emotions and subjective experiences. For instance, when we estimate our own likelihood of suffering from a stroke, the first thing we think about is the amount of people we know who’ve already had one.
If we don’t know anybody who’s had a stroke, we automatically assume that there’s only a low risk that we’ll have one. And so, even if our own risk is actually extremely high, we don’t take any precautions. In order words, our gut feeling has led us first to a misjudgment and then to an unwise decision.
Human beings act mainly on gut feelings.

Sometimes we make faulty decisions because we succumb to temptation or act without thinking.

If you offer a long-time smoker a cigarette while she’s in the process of quitting, it’ll be difficult for her to resist the temptation. Although she’d like to quit and knows how bad it is for her, she’ll probably end up bumming a smoke.
The reason for this unwise response is a lack of will: despite her intentions, the temptation is simply too great. A certain degree of thoughtlessness also takes hold of us in such situations.
For example, experiments have shown that bigger portions cause us to eat more. If we have a big portion in front of us, we eat more of it than we should – even if it doesn’t taste good.
In one experiment, researchers sent their test subjects to the movies. Before they entered the theater, the subjects received a bag of stale popcorn – half got a small bag, the other half a medium-sized bag.
Although most of the participants later stated that the stale popcorn didn’t taste good, they ate a lot of it anyway – and the people with the big bags ate even more of theirs.
Sometimes we make faulty decisions because we succumb to temptation or act without thinking.

Some companies exploit the human tendency to make the wrong decisions.

If companies want to be successful, they have to sell products and earn profits. And to do that, they have to fulfill their customers’ needs.
Whether that has positive or negative consequences on customers doesn’t matter to some companies – their main concern is whether customers are buying.
Sometimes companies don’t just satisfy the needs that customers already have – they can create new needs in their customers too.
For example, many people can’t help themselves in the face of temptation and don’t think twice about the consequences when making spur-of-the-moment decisions. Companies use this knowledge to tempt their customers into buying more than they originally intended. This is the core approach of companies that promote XXL-sized portions instead of normal ones, and the availability of these over-sized portions is one of the reasons why so many people eat far too much.
Trial subscriptions to periodicals are another case where companies exploit human weakness. You can sign up and receive the periodical for free for a certain amount of time, but, if you don’t terminate your subscription within the cancellation period, it is automatically renewed, and you continue receiving the periodical – and paying for it.
Some companies exploit the human tendency to make the wrong decisions.

Defaults are highly effective nudges that cause people to automatically do what’s best for them.

Considering that we don’t rack our brains every time we make a decision, decision-making situations should be designed so that automatic responses produce a positive outcome.
The e-mail service Gmail does just that with its attachment reminder. If words like “please find attached” are written in e-mail text but no file has been attached, the e-mail program automatically recognizes it and asks the user, “Did you want to send an attachment?” This little nudge can save people a lot of time and trouble.
Companies could choose a similar system to assist their employees to make wise decisions about, e.g., enrolling in company pension-scheme programs.
Since most people are naturally inclined to laziness and don’t really want to change their status quo, enrolling in a company pension-scheme program should not be optional. It would be much better to set up the program so that all employees are automatically enrolled in the scheme – and have to explicitly object if they do not want to be.
Companies should choose defaults guaranteeing that employees do the right thing even when the employees do nothing at all.
Defaults are highly effective nudges that cause people to automatically do what’s best for them.

Nudges are most useful when we have too many choices or when the future is at stake.

The most opportune time to use nudges is in situations where it’s particularly difficult for us to make the right decisions.
Making the wrong decision is easy when we have an immediate pay-off and don’t feel the negative consequences until later. We take that second piece of cake and drink that cocktail after work because they give us pleasure in the moment and we only feel the negative effects later – when we step on a scale at the end of the month, or wake up the next morning with a headache.
Another cause of bad decision-making is when we don’t have previous experiences to refer to.
At some point or another, we have to decide on which insurance company we want to use. Since we only make this decision once or twice in our lives, we can’t refer to earlier experiences to assess which insurance company would be best for us.
And even after choosing a health insurance company, there is yet another decision to be made: which policy?
For example, if an insurance company offers many different policies, but some customers who just want general coverage are having difficulty choosing which policy would be best for them, the company could offer a recommended “default policy” – say, one that covers more than 80% of a person’s entire medical costs. This helps the less insurance-savvy customers choose a policy that covers a wide range of treatments for the most common medical problems.
Nudges are most useful when we have too many choices or when the future is at stake.

States and other institutions should use nudges to encourage wise decisions.

Nudges encourage individuals to make better decisions – and this often benefits more than just the individual alone. An entire society benefits when the majority of its members make wise decisions. If fewer people smoke or are overweight, healthcare costs decrease – and everybody wins.
Even though a nudge may cost us something at first, the longer term benefits are generally not long in coming.
In the area of environmental protection, the mere act of instating a public obligation to report carbon emissions has the power to change peoples’ behavior. This obligation doesn’t explicitly forbid companies to exceed a certain limit of pollutant emissions. Instead, it acts as a nudge by creating incentives to voluntarily cut down on emissions (especially because environmentalists frequently use such information to publicly denounce polluters). The reporting obligation thus creates a sort of emission-cutting competition – without using any legal coercion.
As the dollar-a-day program shows, nudges can also reduce the amount of unwanted teenage pregnancies. Many young mothers who’ve already had a child as a teenager often get pregnant again shortly thereafter. In order to tackle this issue, several US cities pay teenage mothers one dollar for every day they don’t get pregnant. This program is actually cheaper for taxpayers than the costs of supporting the children of the young mothers.
Companies also use nudges to keep their customers from making mistakes. If we forget to put on our seat belt in a car, the car beeps at us until we buckle up. If our gas tank is almost empty, a warning light blinks to remind us to stop and fill it up. These little things don’t force us to fasten our seat belts or fill our gas tanks: they do, however, prevent us from accidentally forgetting.
States and other institutions should use nudges to encourage wise decisions.

Final summary

They key message of this book is:
People often make unwise decisions, but the slightest of changes – so-called nudges – can give people incentives to make better decisions. That’s why countries and private institutions should also use nudges.
The questions this book answered:
How and why do we make the wrong decisions?
• We don’t always make decisions that are best for us in the long run.
• We often make bad decisions based on either too little or overly complex information.
• Human beings act mainly on gut feelings.
• Sometimes we make faulty decisions because we succumb to temptation or act without thinking.
• Some companies exploit the human tendency to make the wrong decisions.
How can nudges help us deal with this problem?
• Nudges are subtle changes in context that help us avoid making bad decisions.
• Defaults are highly effective nudges that cause people to automatically do what’s best for them.
• Nudges are most useful when we have too many choices or when the future is at stake.
How can each and every one of us use nudges?
• Many people use nudges to achieve their goals.
• States and other institutions should use nudges to encourage wise decisions.

Be the first to comment

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.


*